Almost
every problem our country faces can be traced to economic inequality. It distorts our politics and makes it harder
to reach the more equitable society we say we want.
Political
scholars Nolan McCarty and Boris Shor have just published a paper with economist John Voorheis with a
potential description of the mechanism that makes it harder to reach consensus
decisions. They show that increasing
levels of economic inequality simultaneously increase the level of political
polarization in state legislatures while also making them more conservative.
When there
is a large degree of economic inequality within a state legislative district,
they argue, the legislators elected from that district become more
conservative, perhaps because the wealthy people in the district gain more
influence.
When there
is a lot of economic inequality between legislative districts in a state, the
legislators become more liberal, they say, because there may be greater demands
for redistribution.
Apparently
what is happening is that as income inequality grows, centrist Democratic
legislators begin to lose elections to Republicans. As more Republicans take their seats in the
state legislatures, the moderating influence of the centrists disappears. That leaves the more liberal Democrats in
place, making the remaining Democratic group more liberal, on average, than
before.
You can see
how this works in Table 1. Imagine that
a state legislature, before the election, has 10 Democrats, and then after the
election, it has only 7. Suppose, also,
that we can arrange the legislators along an ideological continuum that runs
from 1 to 10 with 1 being the most conservative and 10 the most liberal.
Table 1
Legislator
|
Ideology Score
|
1
|
5
|
2
|
6
|
3
|
7
|
4
|
8
|
5
|
8
|
6
|
8
|
7
|
9
|
8
|
9
|
9
|
10
|
10
|
10
|
Ideological Average
|
8.00
|
Now suppose
that legislators 1, 2 and 3 lose their elections to Republicans. The ideological average of the group of
surviving Democratic legislators grows from 8.00 to 8.86.
Even if the
new Republican legislators have ideologies that are equal to the average
ideology score of the legislature’s Republican caucus, the mere fact that the
Democratic caucus is now more liberal will increase the ideological distance
between the two parties. The ideological
distance will increase even more if the people who defeated the incumbent
Democrats are more conservative than the incumbent Republicans.
Increased
polarization is likely to increase rancor between the legislative majority and
the legislative minority, and it becomes less likely that the two parties will
be able to find common ground.
The authors
suggest that these effects reduce “both the appetite and ability of state
legislatures to engage in redistribution, which in turn further increases
income inequality.” The appetite for
redistribution diminishes because there are more Republicans who favor the
discipline of the market. The ability to
pass redistributive legislation decreases because polarization often leads to
legislative gridlock.
Of course,
control of economic policy is not all that is at stake in any state legislative
election. The party that controls the
legislature also controls the rules governing elections. A party that finds itself in control of a
state’s government when redistricting is on the table has an opportunity to
entrench itself in power by redrawing state legislative districts to its own
benefit. It can also reshape the rules
to make it easier for its own voters to reach the polls on Election Day, or,
perhaps more to the point, to make it harder for the other party’s voters to
vote.
And because
state legislatures also establish the boundaries of Congressional districts,
state level and district level income inequality influences who gets elected to
the House of Representatives as well.
If all of
these things are happening, things can’t help but get worse. And, in fact, according to the paper, since
2008, they have.
What the
authors don’t explain is why income inequality tends to hurt the electoral
prospects of Democrats in the first place.
One possibility is that economic inequality reduces the level of
generalized trust
required to keep a society functioning smoothly. As generalized trust diminishes, voters
become less and less willing to agree to greater redistribution, and
politicians promising less redistribution benefit.
But another
possibility is that as a nation, we have simply sorted ourselves into places where our neighbors are more like us than they are
different. It could be that wealthy folk
simply prefer to live in areas with other wealthy folk, and that once an area
reaches a level where inequality is high enough, they have sufficient resources
to dominate the politics of the area even if they are a numerical minority.
Voorheis,
McCarty and Shor, paint an ugly but informative picture of a vicious
cycle. If there is anything to save us,
it is the populist stirrings we’re hearing from virtually all of the
presidential candidates from both parties. We can only hope that it is the real
populism that arises from discussions around kitchen tables and backyard
fences, and not the faux populism manufactured by K Street and Madison Avenue at the behest of
Wall Street.
No comments:
Post a Comment