We
generally want the government to help those who need help. And we expect those who can help themselves
to do so. Yet, our public policy system
seems to get this exactly backwards. The
American government helps the people who most need help least while it helps
the people who least need help the most.
That’s the
conclusion of a new Center for American Progress report written by Christian Weller of the Center for American Progress and Teresa
Ghilarducci of The New School. According
to Weller and Ghilarducci, the American system is extremely inefficient in the
way it incentivizes retirement savings, if it incentivizes them at all.
That, in
large part, is because we use the fun-house mirror world of the Internal
Revenue Code to encourage people to save for retirement instead of directly
subsidizing retirement security through government spending.
To make
this simple, imagine two taxpayers, Alice and Betty. Alice is richer than Betty and pays tax at an
effective rate of 25%. Betty only has to
pay tax at an effective rate of 15%.
Let’s say
that last year, Alice had gross income of $100,000 while Betty had income of
only $50,000. With no deductions Alice
owes $25,000 in taxes while Betty owes only $7,500. That seems fair under a tax system where the
better off have to pay tax at a higher rate.
But now
lets suppose that the government allows both Alice and Betty to deduct or
exclude from taxable income $2,000 for money they each deposited into retirement
savings accounts. That gives Alice
$98,000 in taxable income while it gives Betty $48,000 in taxable income. At their respective rates Alice owes $24,500
while Betty owes $7,200. The deduction
or exclusion reduces Alice’s tax bill by (and is therefore worth) $500. Though Betty deposited the same amount of
money in a retirement account, her tax bill is only $300 lower. Alice’s cost of
savings with the deduction or exclusion is only $1,500 while Betty’s is $1,700.
The first
thing to notice here is that the national government made Alice and Betty
collectively $800 better off than they would have been without the deduction or
exclusion. And it also reduced the
amount of money available to the government to spend on other things by $800 because
now Alice and Betty will be paying the government $800 less than they would
have paid.
Second, the
amount of the benefit depends on the tax rate applied. $500 is 25% the $2,000 Alice deducted and
$300 is 15% of the $2,000 that Betty deducted.
The $200 difference between the value of the deduction to Alice and the
value of the deduction to Betty is 10% of the $2,000 they both deducted, which is
the difference between the tax rate that applies to Alice and the tax rate that
applies to Betty.
The last
thing to notice is that Alice has a bigger incentive to save than Betty, even
though it is likely that, because of her higher income, Alice needs less incentive
to save than does Betty. In fact, because Alice has more income than Betty, she
was probably going to be able to save regardless of whether the government gave
her an incentive to do so. Betty’s
income doesn’t leave her much room to save for retirement, and so if we want
her to save for retirement, she’s probably going to need a bigger incentive.
Weller and
Ghilarducci also point out that Alice and Betty aren’t likely to have the same
opportunities to save. Alice probably
works for a company that makes a tax favored 401(k) retirement plan available
as a payroll deduction while Betty, if she’s going to save, will have to set up
a private IRA. The maximum amount Betty can save in her IRA in any year is
$5,500. But Alice, with access to a
401(k) plan, can contribute up to $18,000 toward her retirement in any year.
Because
Alice’s company has specialists who can design the company’s retirement plan so
that Alice can make a few meaningful choices in how her contributions are
invested and have an automatic payroll deposit of a specified amount deducted
from her paycheck and deposited in her account, the plan is gentle on her
mind. It takes her a few minutes to set
it up and then she can forget about it. There are few if any fees.
Poor Betty
has to do it all on her own. She has to
figure out how to set up her own IRA.
She has to decide whether to use a bank or a brokerage. She has to choose from an almost endless menu
of investment choices. And some of the
investment vehicles will benefit her commissioned investment advisor more than
they will benefit her. Her investment
advisor isn’t yet required to disclose that conflict of interests. And she has to rely on self-discipline to see
that some of her earnings are deposited in her retirement account. Weller and Ghilarducci say that people like
Betty are likely to forgo setting up retirement plans because it’s just too
hard.
Meanwhile,
the government forgoes (and so it spends) over $100 billion in tax revenues
every year that it could otherwise have collected on account of the special tax
treatment of retirement savings accounts.
States forgo (and, therefore spend) about $20 billion.
The lion’s share of this goes to the top 20%
of all earners, three quarters of which goes to the top 10% of all
earners. Only 18% of the benefits of tax
favored retirement accounts goes to the bottom 40% of all earners.
No wonder
we have a retirement crisis on our hands.
Imagine the
uproar that would occur if, instead of trying to incentivize retirement savings
through the tax code, we simply asked the Treasury to write checks to people
like Alice and Betty, correcting for the fact that Betty needs more help than
Alice.
Is there
anybody who thinks Congress would adopt that kind of system?
Probably
the same people who want to cut Social Security.
No comments:
Post a Comment