Dan
Kildee is the Democratic Congressman whose district includes Flint,
Michigan. Last week he proposed
comprehensive legislation focused on providing help to the city whose
population had been poisoned by the carelessness of Michigan’s Department of
Environmental Quality and the “emergency financial managers” appointed by
Governor Rick Snyder.
The measure
would provide federal matching funds to repair Flint’s water distribution
system and provide health monitoring and remedial services for residents
poisoned by the lead leached from pipes by the caustic waters of the Flint
River. Michigan Senators Debbie Stabenow
(D-MI) and Gary Peters (D-MI) have introduced a counterpart measure in the
Senate.
The
liberal/progressive in me wants to stand up and cheer for my fellow
Democrats. Those people in Flint need
help and they need it now. And they apparently
don’t have the political muscle to wring anything but mea culpas and contrite apologies out of Lansing. We’re all
Americans, and if that means anything, it should be that when our fellow
Americans are in trouble we help them out through our national government.
But the
political scientist in me is less enthusiastic.
The Flint catastrophe has queued up a difficult problem that pervades
the Tragic Commons: “moral hazard.”
Moral
hazard exists when people are protected from the adverse consequences of their
actions by some third party. Because of
that protection, people lose the incentive to behave properly. There’s a great example of moral hazard in a scene from the 1991
flick Fried Green Tomatoes. In it, a frustrated older driver loses a
parking space for which she had been patiently waiting to a pair of young women
driving a VW convertible. The older
driver’s enraged and gleefully rams the VW multiple times with her four door
Ford sedan. “Face it, girls” the older driver says, “I’m older and I have more
insurance.”
Like a
number of states captured by Republicans in the wave elections of 2010 and
2014, Michigan adopted substantial
tax cuts. Among other things those
cuts blew a hole in Flint’s budget, enabling the Snyder to appoint a series of
emergency financial managers more interested in cutting costs than in
protecting the public.
There isn’t
any question that the State of Michigan is responsible for the mess in
Flint. Everyone here in the Tragic
Commons thinks that it should be up to Michigan’s taxpayers to clean it up.
Moral
hazard results if the national government steps up to help. Michigan would get to keep its taxes low
while national taxpayers bear the expense of the cleanup. The fact that Kildee’s bill provides funding
only on a matching basis goes some part of the distance in reducing the moral hazard,
but still, from the standpoint of principle, it doesn’t explain why the State
of Michigan and its taxpayers shouldn’t pick up the entire check.
In fact, if
Congress adopts Kildee’s bill or anything like it, Congress would be telling
the States (and the Republican politicians that run them) not to worry about
being fiscally responsible with their tax rates. Moral hazard would encourages states to cut
their tax rates and take comfort in the assurance that if things get really bad
in the state, benevolent taxpayers from the rest of the country will step in
and bail the state out. Moral hazard
would stand the straight-laced Republican insistence on fiscal prudence on its
head.
On the
other hand, there are some in the Tragic Commons who argue that fiscal prudence
requires state and local governments
to try to pass their costs off to suckers not smart enough (or too sentimental)
to object. That is, after all, what the
Tragic Commons is all about.
Looking at
Rep. Kildee’s bill through the lens of moral hazard raises another question: Is
federal assistance for Flint any different from federal assistance for places
like the Jersey Shore, devastated by hurricane Sandy? Should we be more willing
to help people who have been hurt by force majeure
than by human agency?
At first
blush, Hurricane Sandy can be seen as a “one-off” event for which nobody on the
local level had any responsibility. The
damage done to the Jersey Shore occurred because of Mother Nature’s wrath, not
because state and local authorities were asleep at the switch as they were in
Flint.
Yet, the
need for federal assistance depended on available state resources. New Jersey is a coastal state, and its
officials should be able to anticipate that the sea will rise up against it
from time to time. Why shouldn’t we
expect New Jersey to insure itself against such disasters by using its taxing
powers to create a large reserve fund to be used in such cases? Or, to put it another way, how much should the
rest of us be willing to help a state that hasn’t tried to anticipate disaster
by using its tax power to protect itself?
These are
difficult questions, and they go straight to the heart of our federal
system. If we’re going to have a system
in which states are sovereign and have financial control over their
territories, shouldn’t they also have to absorb some substantial portion of a
loss before turning to Washington for additional assistance? Shouldn’t state voters be forced to suffer
the consequences of electing politicians who want to reduce the level of safety
for its residents in order to cut its taxes?
Or, must we
instead recognize that we live in the Tragic Commons, and accept that the cost
of doing the right things for our fellow citizens when their own states won’t
has the potential for turning the rest of us into suckers.
"Moral hazard exists when people are protected from the adverse consequences of their actions by some third party." Which people were protected here and which actions had adverse consequences and what is meant by "protected from"? Surely not the people of Flint who are experiencing the consequences by being poisoned with lead, unless one argues that the hazardous action was "choosing" to live in Flint? Is it the people of Michigan who should be the ones to suffer the financial consequences of the problem in Flint? For what action are they to suffer the consequences? Was it electing Rick Snyder? Snyder received less than 51% of the vote in 2014, so of those who voted, nearly half will be suffering for something they explicitly tried to stop. When we add in the non-voters, we are talking about the majority suffering for an action taken by the minority. This is the definition of collective punishment. And then we have to ask the question if those who did vote for Snyder knew, could have known or should have been able to know that their vote would have the consequence of causing something like the poisoning of Flint (that is if we are somehow able to establish that link).
ReplyDeleteTo me, the actions that entailed moral hazard were those taken by Snyder and his cadre, and so consequences need to be attached to those persons and their actions. In a country with perfect justice and without the need to prove that specific laws have been broken in order to apply that justice, maybe consequences would be born by Snyder going to jail (although someone would still have to pay), or by just those who voted for him, or those who funded him, like the Kochs. The problem here is that like so many nice economic theories, trying to implement it faithfully is a near impossibility. In this case it is not possible to assign the financial consequences of an action to those responsible, so I think that the moral lens we should use is not "moral hazard" but "moral duty", i.e. "the price we all pay for living in a civilized society", where we all bear some of the cost for events which befall some of us when it is not possible to apportion blame/responsibility. In other words, group insurance in the the form of the social safety net. In that light, we could discuss what levels (personal, local, state, federal) should bear what part of the burden of helping those impacted and fixing their problem.